por admin » Vie Jun 18, 2010 6:24 am
Ya Bernanke y una recatafila de economistas serios ha salido a gritarle al gobierno de Obama que US no puede seguir aumentando su gasto y su deficit de manera indiscriminada e irresponsable, que lo que le esta pasando a Grecia y Europa le puede pasar a US en un futuro cercano, que no puede seguir vendiendo deuda como si el deficit no tuviera consecuencias. Aqui tenemos este articulo de Greenspan quien levanta su voz y se une a las que critican duramente a este gobierno. Greenspan dice que US esta libre del riesgo de credito pero no esta libre del riesgo de los intereses. US no puede de la noche a la maniana duplicar la emision de su deuda sin que los intereses que tenga que pagar no suban. Eso va a ocurrir, lamenta que los politicos y legisladores de turno no entiendan la gravedad, seriedad y urgencia del problema.
Dice Greenspan como todos los demas que US tendra que recortar los beneficios de pension, seguro de salud, etc. para poder solucionar el problema de la deuda, esos programas ya establecidos estan quebrados asi como estan, sin contar con el beneficio de salud de Obama recien aprobado.
Dice Greenspan que no favorece el alza de impuestos para reducir el deficit ya que esta medida mermaria el crecimiento de la economia y la competitividad del pais en el mundo.
Dice Greenspan que el no cree que la reduccion del deficit en estos momentos perjudicaria a la economia, piensa que si el gobierno deja de emitir deuda esta accion ayudaria a los mercados de capital privado.
Felizmente dice, la gravedad de los problemas de Grecia han puesto a US en una posicion de buscar una respuesta seria, esa respuesta dice tiene que reconocer que el pais no puede darse el lujo de equivocarse al calcular el costo de los programas sociales a largo plazo especialmente el de medicare. Nuestra economia no puede subestimar el momento corrosivo que se vive en nuestra crisis fiscal. Todas nuestras politicas tienen que estar en el lado de la restriccion del gasto y del deficit.
Tambien alerta que lso recortes de impuestos tienen que estar acompaniados de recortes en el gasto, solos no funcionan.
U.S. Debt and the Greece Analogy
Don't be fooled by today's low interest rates. The government could very quickly discover the limits of its borrowing capacity
By ALAN GREENSPAN
An urgency to rein in budget deficits seems to be gaining some traction among American lawmakers. If so, it is none too soon. Perceptions of a large U.S. borrowing capacity are misleading.
Despite the surge in federal debt to the public during the past 18 months—to $8.6 trillion from $5.5 trillion—inflation and long-term interest rates, the typical symptoms of fiscal excess, have remained remarkably subdued. This is regrettable, because it is fostering a sense of complacency that can have dire consequences.
More on the Deficit
Senate Democrats Defeat GOP Tax, Benefits Bill
Spending Bill Set Back in Senate
Washington Gets Deficit Religion—and a Quandary
More on the Fed
Fed Intact After Challenge to Its Power
Fed's No. 2 Man Says Rules 'Didn't Keep Up'
.The roots of the apparent debt market calm are clear enough. The financial crisis, triggered by the unexpected default of Lehman Brothers in September 2008, created a collapse in global demand that engendered a high degree of deflationary slack in our economy. The very large contraction of private financing demand freed private saving to finance the explosion of federal debt. Although our financial institutions have recovered perceptibly and returned to a degree of solvency, banks, pending a significant increase in capital, remain reluctant to lend.
Beneath the calm, there are market signals that do not bode well for the future. For generations there had been a large buffer between the borrowing capacity of the U.S. government and the level of its debt to the public. But in the aftermath of the Lehman Brothers collapse, that gap began to narrow rapidly. Federal debt to the public rose to 59% of GDP by mid-June 2010 from 38% in September 2008. How much borrowing leeway at current interest rates remains for U.S. Treasury financing is highly uncertain.
View Full Image
David Klein
.The U.S. government can create dollars at will to meet any obligation, and it will doubtless continue to do so. U.S. Treasurys are thus free of credit risk. But they are not free of interest rate risk. If Treasury net debt issuance were to double overnight, for example, newly issued Treasury securities would continue free of credit risk, but the Treasury would have to pay much higher interest rates to market its newly issued securities.
In the wake of recent massive budget deficits, the difference between the 10-year swap rate and 10-year Treasury note yield (the swap spread) declined to an unprecedented negative 13 basis points this March from a positive 77 basis points in September 2008. This indicated that investors were requiring the U.S. Treasury to pay an interest rate higher than rates that prevailed on comparable maturity private swaps.
(A private swap rate is the fixed interest rate required of a private bank or corporation to be exchanged for a series of cash flow payments, based on floating interest rates, for a particular length of time. A dollar swap spread is the swap rate less the interest rate on U.S. Treasury debt of the same maturity.)
At the height of budget surplus euphoria in 2000, the Office of Management and Budget, the Congressional Budget Office and the Federal Reserve foresaw an elimination of marketable federal debt securities outstanding. The 10-year swap spread in August 2000 reached a record 130 basis points. As the projected surplus disappeared and deficits mounted, the 10-year swap spread progressively declined, turning negative this March, and continued to deteriorate until the unexpected euro-zone crisis granted a reprieve to the U.S.
The 10-year swap spread quickly regained positive territory and by June 14 stood at a plus 12 basis points. The sharp decline in the euro-dollar exchange rate since March reflects a large, but temporary, swing in the intermediate demand for U.S. Treasury securities at the expense of euro issues.
The 10-year swap spread understandably has emerged as a sensitive proxy of Treasury borrowing capacity: a so-called canary in the coal mine.
I grant that low long-term interest rates could continue for months, or even well into next year. But just as easily, long-term rate increases can emerge with unexpected suddenness. Between early October 1979 and late February 1980, for example, the yield on the 10-year note rose almost four percentage points.
In the 1950s, as I remember them, U.S. federal budget deficits were no more politically acceptable than households spending beyond their means. Regrettably, that now quaint notion gave way over the decades, such that today it is the rare politician who doesn't run on seemingly costless spending increases or tax cuts with borrowed money. A low tax burden is essential to maintain America's global competitiveness. But tax cuts need to be funded by permanent outlay reductions.
The current federal debt explosion is being driven by an inability to stem new spending initiatives. Having appropriated hundreds of billions of dollars on new programs in the last year and a half, it is very difficult for Congress to deny an additional one or two billion dollars for programs that significant constituencies perceive as urgent. The federal government is currently saddled with commitments for the next three decades that it will be unable to meet in real terms. This is not new. For at least a quarter century analysts have been aware of the pending surge in baby boomer retirees.
We cannot grow out of these fiscal pressures. The modest-sized post-baby-boom labor force, if history is any guide, will not be able to consistently increase output per hour by more than 3% annually. The product of a slowly growing labor force and limited productivity growth will not provide the real resources necessary to meet existing commitments. (We must avoid persistent borrowing from abroad. We cannot count on foreigners to finance our current account deficit indefinitely.)
Only politically toxic cuts or rationing of medical care, a marked rise in the eligible age for health and retirement benefits, or significant inflation, can close the deficit. I rule out large tax increases that would sap economic growth (and the tax base) and accordingly achieve little added revenues.
With huge deficits currently having no evident effect on either inflation or long-term interest rates, the budget constraints of the past are missing. It is little comfort that the dollar is still the least worst of the major fiat currencies. But the inexorable rise in the price of gold indicates a large number of investors are seeking a safe haven beyond fiat currencies.
The United States, and most of the rest of the developed world, is in need of a tectonic shift in fiscal policy. Incremental change will not be adequate. In the past decade the U.S. has been unable to cut any federal spending programs of significance.
I believe the fears of budget contraction inducing a renewed decline of economic activity are misplaced. The current spending momentum is so pressing that it is highly unlikely that any politically feasible fiscal constraint will unleash new deflationary forces. I do not believe that our lawmakers or others are aware of the degree of impairment of our fiscal brakes. If we contained the amount of issuance of Treasury securities, pressures on private capital markets would be eased.
Fortunately, the very severity of the pending crisis and growing analogies to Greece set the stage for a serious response. That response needs to recognize that the range of error of long-term U.S. budget forecasts (especially of Medicare) is, in historic perspective, exceptionally wide. Our economy cannot afford a major mistake in underestimating the corrosive momentum of this fiscal crisis. Our policy focus must therefore err significantly on the side of restraint.
Mr. Greenspan, former chairman of the Federal Reserve, is president of Greenspan Associates LLC and author of "The Age of Turbulence: Adventures in a New World" (Penguin, 2007).